Insurance, Developing Countries and Climate Change
More than three-quarters of recent economic losses caused by natural hazards can be attributed to windstorms, floods, droughts and other climate-related hazards, which appear to be increasing at a greater rate than geophysical disasters.
This trend can be largely attributed to changes in land use and increasing concentration of people and capital in vulnerable areas, for example, in coastal regions exposed to windstorms and in fertile river basins exposed to floods.
As indicated by the greater increase in weather-related disasters compared to geophysical disasters, climate change also appears to be a factor in increased disaster losses.
The Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change has predicted that climate change will increase weather variability as well as the intensity and frequency of weather-related extremes. There is also mounting evidence that climate change is contributing to increasing current risks.
In the past quarter-century, over 95 per cent of deaths from natural disasters occurred in developing countries, and direct economic losses (averaging US$100 billion per annum in the last decade) in relation to national income were more than twice as high in low-income as opposed to high-income countries.
These disaster statistics do not (for the most part) reflect long-term indirect losses, which can be very significant, particularly in countries with little capacity to respond and recover.
Not only are there considerable differences in the human and economic burden of disasters in developed versus developing countries, but also in insurance cover.
In the richest countries about 30 per cent of losses in the period 1980–2004 (totalling about 3.7 per cent of Gross National Product (GNP) were insured; in low-income countries, only about 1 per cent of losses (amounting to 12.9 per cent of GNP) were insured.
Owing to the lack of insurance, combined with exhausted tax bases, high levels of indebtedness and limited donor assistance, many highly exposed developing countries cannot raise sufficient capital to replace or repair damaged assets and restore livelihoods following major disasters, exacerbating the impacts of disaster shocks on poverty and development.
Developing countries with very low catastrophe insurance penetration represent a challenging and under-served market for the private insurance sector.
Entrepreneurs are beginning to find ways to provide insurance for the lower end of the market, particularly through micro-insurance products that are made accessible by support from civil society and the public sector.
This market is only feasible if premiums are affordable to the poor, which opens an opportunity for negotiators seeking opportunities for helping the most vulnerable adapt to climate change.
The case for including insurance and other risk-transfer instruments in a climate adaptation strategy builds on a growing recognition that the developed world, because of its emissions of greenhouse gases, is contributing to weather-related losses in the developing world.
The so-called Copenhagen Agreed Outcome, which will determine the new post-2012 international climate regime, is expected to include both targets and action plans for the reduction of greenhouse gases (mitigation) as well as a framework to facilitate adaptation to the negative effects of climate change that can no longer be mitigated.
It is under the adaptation agenda that insurance solutions are now under serious consideration. The MCII has proposed a climate risk management module to be included in the adaptation agenda.
Fully funded by an adaptation fund or other financial mechanism emerging from climate negotiations in Copenhagen in 2009, this module would provide support for weather-related disaster prevention and insurance in vulnerable countries.
This paper presents the insurance ‘‘pillar’’ of MCII’s proposed risk management module. As background, we begin in the next section by discussing the status of micro- and sovereign-catastrophe insurance programmes currently in place for serving developing country households, businesses and governments.
In the third section, we examine their benefits, risks, costs and affordability. We argue that the private sector, acting alone, cannot provide adequate security to low-income clients, an argument that forms the rationale for support from a climate adaptation strategy.
The rationale for including insurance in a climate adaptation regime rests not only on the failure of the market to serve the most vulnerable, but as we argue in the fourth section, it is also based on the prospect that insurance mechanisms can help reduce the impacts of these events.
In the fifth section, we describe the MCII proposal for a twotiered Insurance Pillar, financed by a Copenhagen Agreed Outcome financial mechanism, to (1) absorb a part of the high-level risks in vulnerable countries; and (2) enable micro- and sovereign-insurance systems to absorb middle layer risks.
This Insurance Pillar would be part of a broader climate risk management strategy, which includes an interlinked prevention pillar.
A. Disaster risk financing in developing countries
Insurance instruments are only one of many activities involved in managing risks of natural hazards. The first, and arguably the highest priority in risk management, is investing in preventing or mitigating human and economic losses.
Disaster mitigation and prevention can take many forms: reducing exposure to risks, (e.g. land-use planning); reducing vulnerability (e.g. retrofitting high-risk buildings) or creating institutions for better response (e.g. emergency planning).
The residual risk can then be managed with insurance and other risk-financing strategies for the purpose of providing timely relief and assuring an effective recovery. Importantly, insurance can be designed to reward preventive behaviour, and in this way it can directly contribute to disaster loss reduction.
Most commercial disaster insurance is held by citizens of high-income countries (per capital income greater than US$9,361), although even in these countries less than a third of disaster losses are insured. Not surprisingly, the picture is quite different for countries outside of the high-income bracket.
Insurance density drops from around a third to less than a tenth in emerging economy countries, and it is almost negligible (1–2 per cent) in low-middle and low-income developing countries.
As pictured below, in the U.S., parts of Europe and Australia, the average person pays over US$500 in property insurance premium compared to Africa and parts of Asia with less than US$5 in premium (Figure 1).
Instead of insurance, households and businesses rely extensively on post-disaster public assistance. This is the case even in high-income countries. In the U.S., for instance, the federal government provides extensive assistance to private victims.
Taking the 1994 Northridge earthquake as an example, only about 30 per cent of total direct private and public losses were absorbed by private insurance companies.
In stark contrast, in the U.K., which claims 75 per cent flood insurance penetration, the government gives little assistance to private victims. As noted above, insurance is practically non-existent in least developed countries, and public assistance tends to be far lower.
As a typical case, after the severe flooding in Sudan in 1998, the victims themselves absorbed over 80 per cent of the losses. In addition to relying on public assistance, households, farmers and governments in the developing world have many opportunities for financing their recovery after disasters.
As shown in Table 1, individuals can take out emergency loans from their family, micro-credit institutions or money lenders; sell or mortgage assets and land or rely on public and international aid.
Likewise, governments raise post-disaster capital by diverting funds from other budgeted programmes, borrowing money domestically or taking loans from international financial institutions.
Individuals may also make arrangements before the disaster: setting up mutual arrangements with family, microsavings and food storage. Similarly, governments can spread risks temporally or spatially by putting a reserve fund in place, making contingent credit arrangements or forming regional pools.
These informal mechanisms for financing disasters can be less costly and thus more affordable and accessible to very low-income individuals and governments.
Yet, although informal financing appears to work reasonably well for low-loss events, it is often unreliable and inadequate for catastrophic events. At the public level, it is well known that if governments can spread their post-disaster costs over a large tax base, or other lower-cost financing strategies, they should be risk neutral and not purchase insurance.
However, in the aftermath of heavy devastation in their countries, lowincome developing countries may face exhausted tax bases, little reserves and declining credit ratings making external borrowing difficult.
Finally, external assistance is limited, and with the exception of highly publicised disasters it is usually inadequate to meet post-disaster needs. International support for victims of the 2006 Indian Ocean tsunami was estimated at about $7,000 per affected victim, which was exceptional.
On average, international post-disaster assistance has approximated 10 per cent of direct economic losses,13 and it can be much less. For example, support for victims of the devastating floods affecting Bangladesh in 1998 was estimated at about US$3 per affected victim.
Nor can governments rely on postdisaster assistance. As a typical case, 2 years following the 2001 earthquake in Gujarat, assistance from international sources had reached only 20 per cent of original commitments.
The inaccessibility of sufficient and affordable capital to support the recovery process in highly vulnerable countries is the main rationale for donor organisations, and also for a climate adaptation regime, to provide assistance to insurance programmes.
Switching from post-disaster humanitarian assistance to providing predisaster security through insurance instruments also has benefits to donors.16 Because insurance instruments can provide strong incentives for reducing risks, a point we will cover later, ex-ante support of insurance eventually reduces the need for outside assistance.
B. Disaster insurance for developing countries
Donors and international financial institutions are increasingly supporting insurance systems in the developing world. A number of innovative pilot programmes are providing insurance to farmers, property owners and small businesses, as well as transferring the risks facing governments to the international capital markets.
Examples include index-based crop and livestock insurance systems in Malawi and Mongolia, property insurance in Turkey; a regional catastrophe insurance pool for the Caribbean Island States,21 and the issuance of a catastrophe bond by the Mexican government.
These and other donor-supported insurance systems are for the most part still in a pilot stage, and none has experienced a major and widespread catastrophic event. It is too early, thus, to fully assess their effectiveness in reducing economic insecurity.
In examining this early experience, the broader question arises whether developing countries should, indeed, follow the path of the developed world in insuring against catastrophic events, and which insurance instruments and modifications may be appropriate for better tackling the developmental dimensions of natural disasters?
This question is especially topical given the insurance controversies following Hurricane Katrina’s devastation of poor communities in New Orleans. In what follows, we briefly discuss the benefits, risks, costs and affordability of disaster insurance based on early experience in developing countries.
1. Benefits
By providing low-income households, farmers and businesses with the right to postdisaster liquidity, thus securing their livelihoods, insurance instruments can lessen the burdens from disasters and expedite the recovery process.
For many, an insurance contract is more dignified and secure than dependency on the ad hoc generosity of donors. As insured households and farms are more creditworthy, insurance can also promote investments in productive assets and higher-risk/higher-yield activities.
Insurance instruments, if designed carefully to avoid moral hazard, can also provide incentives to reduce risk, a point we will return to in the next section. For governments, insurance instruments can also have large pay-offs by reducing the risk of a post-disaster financial gap and thus ensuring the timely repair of public infrastructure and provision of relief expenditures.
Just like investments in prevention, timely relief and reconstruction can save lives and livelihoods and prevent disaster-induced poverty traps. With internationally backed risk-transfer programmes, developing country governments will rely less on debt financing and international donations, and assured funds for repairing critical infrastructure will attract foreign investment.
2. Risks
As recent and past experience in developing and developed countries shows, there are also risks to an insurance strategy. Broadly, these risks can be categorised as resulting from:
- the potential insolvency and non-sustainability of insurance systems;
- moral hazard, adverse selection and basis risk; and
- institutional stability, public confidence and trust.
Posting Komentar untuk "Insurance, Developing Countries and Climate Change"